Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Skip to main content
null
Findings
  • Menu
  • Articles
    • Energy Findings
    • Resilience Findings
    • Safety Findings
    • Transport Findings
    • Urban Findings
    • All
  • For Authors
  • Editorial Board
  • About
  • Blog
  • covid-19
  • search

RSS Feed

Enter the URL below into your favorite RSS reader.

https://findingspress.org/feed
Energy Findings
March 20, 2024 AEST

Effects of Electricity Sector Climate Policies in a Second-best World of Missing Risk Markets

Emil Dimanchev, Stein-Erik Fleten, Steven A Gabriel, Magnus Korpas,
investment riskincomplete marketsrisk aversionmacro-energy systemsclimate policytax creditscarbon pricing
Copyright Logoccby-sa-4.0 • https://doi.org/10.32866/001c.94993
Findings
Dimanchev, Emil, Stein-Erik Fleten, Steven A Gabriel, and Magnus Korpas. 2024. “Effects of Electricity Sector Climate Policies in a Second-Best World of Missing Risk Markets.” Findings, March. https:/​/​doi.org/​10.32866/​001c.94993.
Save article as...▾
Download all (4)
  • Figure 1. In a power system with missing markets, wind and solar tax credits reduce more CO2 emissions (b.) at a lower cost (d.), thus costing less per ton CO2 reduced
    Download
  • Figure 2. Missing markets lead to sub-optimally little spending on renewables and storage
    Download
  • Figure 3. In a power system with missing markets, CO2 taxes reduce more CO2 emissions (b.) at a lower cost (d.), thus costing less per ton CO2 reduced
    Download
  • Supplementary methodological information and sensitivity analysis
    Download

Sorry, something went wrong. Please try again.

If this problem reoccurs, please contact Scholastica Support

Error message:

undefined

View more stats

Abstract

Analyses of climate policies often assume the economy is in a first-best equilibrium with well-functioning markets. This paper studies policy effects in power systems characterized by a market failure known as the missing market problem, whereby the incompleteness of long-term markets leaves investors exposed to uninsured risk. We find that renewable tax credits and CO2 taxes may partly correct this market failure, thus providing an economic benefit additional to climate change mitigation. Consequently, illustrative experiments show the costs of these policies to be lower, and in some cases even negative, in power systems with missing risk markets.

1. Questions

To assess the possible future effects of climate policies on power systems, decision makers often rely on generation expansion models (Bistline et al. 2023). Such models estimate the optimal set of investment and operating decisions of power market participants. While state-of-the-art models are technologically rich, they often greatly simplify the role of risk in power systems.

Policy analyses commonly assume the existence of idealized markets that allow investors to insure themselves against any possible future. However, real markets fail to provide for such complete risk hedging (Radner 1970). In power systems, this is illustrated by the limited liquidity of long-term markets (Batlle et al. 2023), which is known as the missing market problem (Newbery 2016). As a result, investors face considerable risk, which can cause under-investment. We consider the implications of this phenomenon for government efforts to incentivize clean energy investments.

Specifically, we ask: how are the effectiveness and cost of popular climate policies affected by the missing market problem? Our focus is on Investment Tax Credits (ITCs), such as those in the U.S. Inflation Reduction Act, and CO2 taxes.

2. Methods

We model a power system with risk-averse investors and risk-averse consumers participating in a perfectly competitive, energy-only market. To assess the impact of the missing market problem, we compare two cases. First, in a benchmark, “complete markets” case, investors and consumers share risk by trading long-term contracts. This is represented, as in prior work, by modeling the electricity market as the cost-minimization problem of a risk-averse central planner (Dimanchev et al. 2023). Second, in our main, “missing markets” case, investors and consumers do not trade long-term contracts. To model this, we use the equilibrium model developed by Dimanchev et al. (2023). This model disaggregates investor and consumer decision-making, precluding risk sharing (i.e., long-term contracts) between market participants. In all other respects, the model is equivalent to the complete market benchmark. Sensitivity analyses further compare our modeling to more traditional models that assume risk-neutral agents or that omit uncertainty entirely (supplementary document Section S3).

In our illustrative experiments, risk-averse investors optimally deploy gas plants, wind, solar, and Li-ion batteries. These resources are operated in a least-cost way by a system operator at an hourly resolution in different scenarios for 2050. Meteorological variability is captured in detail using 16 representative weeks based on data for the New England power system (Dimanchev et al. 2023). Investments are made under uncertainty in overall demand, which captures uncertainty in electrification and hydrogen electrolysis. This is represented with four equi-probable scenarios, where demand in each hour is shifted by -25%, -12.5%, +12.5% and +25% relative to projected demand. Risk aversion is modeled using the commonly employed Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR). The model’s formulation is shown in the supplementary document (Section S1).

We measure policy effectiveness as a reduction in power system emissions resulting from a given policy. Policy cost is defined as an increase in risk-adjusted system cost. We use risk-adjusted system cost to represent the perspective of a government that considers the risk preferences of market participants (and therefore risk-adjusts its measure of total costs), as recommended for benefit-cost analyses (OMB 2023). In our context, this is equivalent to the perspective of a government aiming to maximize social welfare, reflective of private risk preferences. The supplementary document provides the mathematical formulation used for calculating the risk-adjusted system cost (Section S2.2) and a sensitivity test using risk-neutral system costs (S4), where our main findings continue to hold.

3. Findings

Power system outcomes with different ITCs are displayed in Figure 1-a/c. Expected emissions are generally higher in the case of missing markets (Figure 1-a). This is because the missing market problem skews investments away from wind and solar in our experiments, as discussed in Dimanchev et al. (2023) and illustrated in Figure 2. This result suggests that renewable investment is sub-optimally low in economies with missing risk markets. Under-investment in renewables and other technologies results in higher risk-adjusted system costs, in part by leading to unserved demand, when risk markets are missing relative to a case of complete markets (Figure 1-c, and Figure 2).

Figure 1
Figure 1.In a power system with missing markets, wind and solar tax credits reduce more CO2 emissions (b.) at a lower cost (d.), thus costing less per ton CO2 reduced

Right panels show changes in outcomes relative to no policy (i.e., the differences in the corresponding left panel between a given result and the result for 0% tax credits)

Figure 2
Figure 2.Missing markets lead to sub-optimally little spending on renewables and storage

The uncertain future costs (generation and load shedding) are risk-adjusted using CVaR to reflect market participants’ risk aversion

We find that the costs of ITCs are lower when long-term markets are missing than when markets are complete (Figure 1-d). This is because ITC policy has two counterveiling effects in the missing markets case. First, as expected, ITCs impose a cost by distorting the market equilibrium. Second, ITCs provide an economic benefit by counteracting inefficiencies caused by the missing market problem. The existence of this second effect is an example of the well-established potential for government interventions to provide economic benefits when the economy is in a second-best equilibrium (Lipsey and Lancaster 1956), a classic case being the revenue recycling effect of environmental taxes amid pre-existing tax distortions (Goulder et al. 1999). Since the missing market problem distorts investments away from wind and solar, its effects are partly corrected by ITCs, which encourage investment in these technologies (Figure 2). The additional investments reduce operating costs, especially in the highest-demand scenario, which is of particular importance to risk-averse consumers. Remarkably, we estimate ITC costs to be negative (Figure 1-d). This indicates that the second of the two effects discussed above outweighs the first (sensitivity tests are provided in the supplementary document sections S4-5).

We also observe that policy effectiveness is higher in the case of missing markets relative to complete markets (Figure 1-b). This can be explained by the fact that emissions in the latter case are lower to begin with, making additional reductions more difficult. In combination with our cost estimates, this result shows that policy efficiency is higher with missing markets (i.e., average cost per ton CO2 abated is lower).

A CO2 tax also corrects missing market inefficiencies, making its economic cost lower when long-term markets are missing (Figure 3-d). By raising the variable cost of the price-setting gas plant, the tax increases renewable revenues, encouraging greater (and more efficient) levels of renewable investment. Our illustrative experiments also show CO2 tax costs to be negative in the presence of missing markets (see supplementary document sections S4-5 for sensitivity tests). The CO2 tax reduces more emissions under missing markets (Figure 3-b). This further implies that CO2 taxes cost less per ton CO2 abated when risk markets are missing.

Figure 3
Figure 3.In a power system with missing markets, CO2 taxes reduce more CO2 emissions (b.) at a lower cost (d.), thus costing less per ton CO2 reduced

Right panels show changes in outcomes relative to no policy (i.e., the differences in the corresponding left panel between a given result and the result for a $0/tCO2 carbon tax)

We expect the real-world effects of the missing market problem to be smaller than what we observe, as economies generally feature some risk trading, though incomplete. This and other assumptions, such as our limited technological options and lack of demand-side flexibility, make our results merely illustrative. Nevertheless our findings suggest a need for further consideration of the missing market problem in climate policy analyses.


Acknowledgements

We thank three anonymous reviewers for helpful feedback. This research was funded by CINELDI, an 8 year research center part of the Norwegian Centers for Environment-friendly Energy Research (FME) (grant number: 257626).

Submitted: January 23, 2024 AEST

Accepted: March 12, 2024 AEST

References

Batlle, Carlos, Tim Schittekatte, Paolo Mastropietro, and Pablo Rodilla. 2023. “The EU Commission’s Proposal for Improving the Electricity Market Design: Treading Water, but Not Drowning.” Current Sustainable/Renewable Energy Reports 10 (4): 197–205. https:/​/​doi.org/​10.1007/​s40518-023-00223-4.
Google Scholar
Bistline, John E T, Maxwell Brown, Maya Domeshek, Cara Marcy, Nicholas Roy, Geoffrey Blanford, Dallas Burtraw, et al. 2023. “Power Sector Impacts of the Inflation Reduction Act of 2022.” Environmental Research Letters 19 (1): 014013. https:/​/​doi.org/​10.1088/​1748-9326/​ad0d3b.
Google Scholar
Dimanchev, Emil, Steven A. Gabriel, Lina Reichenberg, and Magnus Korpaas. 2023. “Consequences of the Missing Risk Market Problem for Power System Emissions.” MIT CEEPR Working Paper Series. MIT CEEPR Working Paper Series: MIT CEEPR Working Paper Series. https:/​/​ceepr.mit.edu/​workingpaper/​consequences-of-the-missing-risk-market-problem-for-power-system-emissions/​.
Goulder, Lawrence H., Ian W.H. Parry, Roberton C. Williams III, and Dallas Burtraw. 1999. “The Cost-Effectiveness of Alternative Instruments for Environmental Protection in a Second-Best Setting.” Journal of Public Economics 72 (3): 329–60. https:/​/​doi.org/​10.1016/​s0047-2727(98)00109-1.
Google Scholar
Lipsey, R. G., and Kelvin Lancaster. 1956. “The General Theory of Second Best.” The Review of Economic Studies 24 (1): 11. https:/​/​doi.org/​10.2307/​2296233.
Google Scholar
Newbery, David. 2016. “Missing Money and Missing Markets: Reliability, Capacity Auctions and Interconnectors.” Energy Policy 94 (July):401–10. https:/​/​doi.org/​10.1016/​j.enpol.2015.10.028.
Google Scholar
OMB. 2023. “Circular No. A-4.” The White House. 2023. https:/​/​www.whitehouse.gov/​wp-content/​uploads/​2023/​11/​CircularA-4.pdf.
Radner, Roy. 1970. “Problems in the Theory of Markets under Uncertainty.” The American Economic Review 60 (2): 454–60.
Google Scholar

This website uses cookies

We use cookies to enhance your experience and support COUNTER Metrics for transparent reporting of readership statistics. Cookie data is not sold to third parties or used for marketing purposes.

Powered by Scholastica, the modern academic journal management system